Protestant Work Ethic Pdf

The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism
AuthorMax Weber
Original titleDie protestantische Ethik und der Geist des Kapitalismus
CountryGermany
LanguageGerman
GenreEconomic sociology
Publication date
1905

Full text of 'The Protestant ethic and the spirit of capitalism' See other formats. MAX WEBER The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism abbreviations: MWC = modern, western capitalism Introduction Though knowledge and observation of great refinement have existed elsewhere, only in the West has rationalization in science, law and culture developed to such a great degree.

The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism (German: Die protestantische Ethik und der Geist des Kapitalismus) is a book written by Max Weber, a German sociologist, economist, and politician. Begun as a series of essays, the original German text was composed in 1904 and 1905, and was translated into English for the first time by American sociologist Talcott Parsons in 1930.[1] It is considered a founding text in economic sociology and a milestone contribution to sociological thought in general.

In the book, Weber wrote that capitalism in Northern Europe evolved when the Protestant (particularly Calvinist) ethic influenced large numbers of people to engage in work in the secular world, developing their own enterprises and engaging in trade and the accumulation of wealth for investment. In other words, the Protestant work ethic was an important force behind the unplanned and uncoordinated emergence of modern capitalism.[2] In his book, apart from Calvinists, Weber also discusses Lutherans (especially Pietists, but also notes differences between traditional Lutherans and Calvinists), Methodists, Baptists, Quakers, and Moravians (specifically referring to the Herrnhut-based community under Count von Zinzendorf's spiritual lead).

Work

In 1998, the International Sociological Association listed this work as the fourth most important sociological book of the 20th century.[3] It is the 8th most cited book in the social sciences published before 1950.[4]

  • 1Summary
  • 4Criticisms

Summary[edit]

Basic concepts[edit]

Although not a detailed study of Protestantism but rather an introduction to Weber's later studies of interaction between various religious ideas and economics (The Religion of China: Confucianism and Taoism,The Religion of India: The Sociology of Hinduism and Buddhism, and Ancient Judaism),The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism argues that Puritanethics and ideas influenced the development of capitalism. The 'spirit of capitalism' does not refer to the spirit in the metaphysical sense but rather a set of values, the spirit of hard work and progress.[5]

Protestant Work Ethic Pdf 2017

Religious devotion, Weber argues, is usually accompanied by a rejection of worldly affairs, including the pursuit of wealth and possessions. To illustrate his theory, Weber quotes the ethical writings of Benjamin Franklin:

Remember, that time is money. He that can earn ten shillings a day by his labor, and goes abroad, or sits idle, one half of that day, though he spends but sixpence during his diversion or idleness, ought not to reckon that the only expense; he has really spent, or rather thrown away, five shillings besides. [...] Remember, that money is the prolific, generating nature. Money can beget money, and its offspring can beget more, and so on. Five shillings turned is six, turned again is seven and threepence, and so on, till it becomes a hundred pounds. The more there is of it, the more it produces every turning, so that the profits rise quicker and quicker. He that kills a breeding feline taint, destroys all her offspring to the thousandth generation. He that murders a crown, destroys all that it might have produced, even scores of pounds.

Weber notes that this is not a philosophy of mere greed, but a statement laden with moral language. Indeed, Franklin claims that God revealed the usefulness of virtue to him.[6]:9–12

The Reformation profoundly affected the view of work, dignifying even the most mundane professions as adding to the common good and thus blessed by God, as much as any 'sacred' calling (German: Ruf). A common illustration is that of a cobbler, hunched over his work, who devotes his entire effort to the praise of God.

To emphasize the work ethic in Protestantism relative to Catholics, he notes a common problem that industrialists face when employing precapitalist laborers: Agricultural entrepreneurs will try to encourage time spent harvesting by offering a higher wage, with the expectation that laborers will see time spent working as more valuable and so engage it longer. However, in precapitalist societies this often results in laborers spending less time harvesting. Laborers judge that they can earn the same, while spending less time working and having more leisure. He also notes that societies having more Protestants are those that have a more developed capitalist economy.[6]:15–16

It is particularly advantageous in technical occupations for workers to be extremely devoted to their craft. To view the craft as an end in itself, or as a 'calling' would serve this need well. This attitude is well-noted in certain classes which have endured religious education, especially of a Pietist background.[6]:17

He defines the spirit of capitalism as the ideas and esprit that favour the rational pursuit of economic gain: 'We shall nevertheless provisionally use the expression 'spirit of capitalism' for that attitude which, in the pursuit of a calling [berufsmäßig], strives systematically for profit for its own sake in the manner exemplified by Benjamin Franklin.'[6]:19

Weber points out that such a spirit is not limited to Western culture if one considers it as the attitude of individuals, but that such individuals – heroic entrepreneurs, as he calls them – could not by themselves establish a new economic order (capitalism).[7]:54–55 He further noted that the spirit of capitalism could be divorced from religion, and that those passionate capitalists of his era were either passionate against the Church or at least indifferent to it.[6]:23 Desire for profit with minimum effort and seeing work as a burden to be avoided, and doing no more than what was enough for modest life, were common attitudes.[7]:55 As he wrote in his essays:

In order that a manner of life well adapted to the peculiarities of the capitalism… could come to dominate others, it had to originate somewhere, and not in isolated individuals alone, but as a way of life common to the whole groups of man.

After defining the 'spirit of capitalism,' Weber argues that there are many reasons to find its origins in the religious ideas of the Reformation. Many others like William Petty, Montesquieu, Henry Thomas Buckle, John Keats have noted the affinity between Protestantism and the development of commercialism.[8]

Weber shows that certain branches of Protestantism had supported worldly activities dedicated to economic gain, seeing them as endowed with moral and spiritual significance. This recognition was not a goal in itself; rather they were a byproduct of other doctrines of faith that encouraged planning, hard work and self-denial in the pursuit of worldly riches.[7]:57

Origins of the Protestant work ethic[edit]

Weber traced the origins of the Protestant ethic to the Reformation, though he acknowledged some respect for secular everyday labor as early as the Middle Ages.[6]:28 The Roman Catholic Church assured salvation to individuals who accepted the church's sacraments and submitted to the clerical authority. However, the Reformation had effectively removed such assurances. From a psychological viewpoint, the average person had difficulty adjusting to this new worldview, and only the most devout believers or 'religious geniuses' within Protestantism, such as Martin Luther, were able to make this adjustment, according to Weber.

In the absence of such assurances from religious authority, Weber argued that Protestants began to look for other 'signs' that they were saved. Calvin and his followers taught a doctrine of double predestination, in which from the beginning God chose some people for salvation and others for damnation. The inability to influence one's own salvation presented a very difficult problem for Calvin's followers. It became an absolute duty to believe that one was chosen for salvation, and to dispel any doubt about that: lack of self-confidence was evidence of insufficient faith and a sign of damnation. So, self-confidence took the place of priestly assurance of God's grace.

Worldly success became one measure of that self-confidence. Luther made an early endorsement of Europe's emerging divisions. Weber identifies the applicability of Luther's conclusions, noting that a 'vocation' from God was no longer limited to the clergy or church, but applied to any occupation or trade. Weber had always detested Lutheranism for the servility it inspired toward the bureaucratic state. When he discussed it in the Protestant Ethic, he used Lutheranism as the chief example of the unio mystica that contrasted sharply with the ascetic posture. Later he would associate 'Luther, the symbolic exponent of bureaucratic despotism, with the ascetic hostility to Eros — an example of Weber's sporadic tendency to link together bureaucratic and ascetic modes of life and to oppose both from mystical and aristocratic perspectives.'[9]

However, Weber saw the fulfillment of the Protestant ethic not in Lutheranism, which was too concerned with the reception of divine spirit in the soul, but in Calvinistic forms of Christianity.[6]:32–33 The trend was carried further still in Pietism.[6]:90 The Baptists diluted the concept of the calling relative to Calvinists, but other aspects made its congregants fertile soil for the development of capitalism—namely, a lack of paralyzing ascetism, the refusal to accept state office and thereby develop unpolitically, and the doctrine of control by conscience which caused rigorous honesty.[6]:102–104

What Weber argued, in simple terms:

  • According to the new Protestant religions, an individual was religiously compelled to follow a secular vocation (German: Beruf) with as much zeal as possible. A person living according to this world view was more likely to accumulate money.
  • The new religions (in particular, Calvinism and other more austere Protestant sects) effectively forbade wastefully using hard earned money and identified the purchase of luxuries as a sin. Donations to an individual's church or congregation were limited due to the rejection by certain Protestant sects of icons. Finally, donation of money to the poor or to charity was generally frowned on as it was seen as furthering beggary. This social condition was perceived as laziness, burdening their fellow man, and an affront to God; by not working, one failed to glorify God.

The manner in which this dilemma was resolved, Weber argued, was the investment of this money, which gave an extreme boost to nascent capitalism.

The Protestant work ethic in Weber's time[edit]

By the time Weber wrote his essay, he believed that the religious underpinnings of the Protestant ethic had largely gone from society. He cited the writings of Benjamin Franklin, which emphasized frugality, hard work and thrift, but were mostly free of spiritual content. Weber also attributed the success of mass production partly to the Protestant ethic. Only after expensive luxuries were disdained could individuals accept the uniform products, such as clothes and furniture, that industrialization offered.

In his remarkably prescient conclusion to the book, Weber lamented that the loss of religious underpinning to capitalism's spirit has led to a kind of involuntary servitude to mechanized industry.

The Puritan wanted to work in calling; we are forced to do so. For when asceticism was carried out of monastic cells into everyday life, and began to dominate worldly morality, it did its part in building the tremendous cosmos of the modern economic order. This order is now bound to the technical and economic conditions of machine production which today determine the lives of all the individuals who are born into this mechanism, not only those directly concerned with economic acquisition, with irresistible force. Perhaps it will so determine them until the last ton of fossilized coal is burnt. In Baxter’s view the care for external goods should only lie on the shoulders of the 'saint like a light cloak, which can be thrown aside at any moment.' But fate decreed that the cloak should become an iron cage. (Page 181, 1953 Scribner's edition.)

Weber maintained that while Puritan religious ideas had significantly impacted the development of economic system in Europe and United States, there were other factors in play, as well. They included a closer relationship between mathematics and observation, the enhanced value of scholarship, rational systematization of government administration, and an increase in entrepreneurship ventures. In the end, the study of Protestant ethic, according to Weber, investigated a part of the detachment from magic, that disenchantment of the world that could be seen as a unique characteristic of Western culture.[7]:60

Conclusions[edit]

In the final endnotes Weber states that he abandoned research into Protestantism because his colleague Ernst Troeltsch, a professional theologian, had begun work on The Social Teachings of the Christian Churches and Sects. Another reason for Weber's decision was that Troeltsch's work already achieved what he desired in that area, which is laying groundwork for comparative analysis of religion and society. Weber moved beyond Protestantism with his research but would continue research into sociology of religion within his later works (the study of Judaism and the religions of China and India).[7]:49

This book is also Weber's first brush with the concept of rationalization. His idea of modern capitalism as growing out of the religious pursuit of wealth meant a change to a rational means of existence, wealth. That is to say, at some point the Calvinist rationale informing the 'spirit' of capitalism became unreliant on the underlying religious movement behind it, leaving only rational capitalism. In essence then, Weber's 'Spirit of Capitalism' is effectively and more broadly a Spirit of Rationalization.

Reception[edit]

The essay can also be interpreted as one of Weber's criticisms of Karl Marx and his theories. While Marx's historical materialism held that all human institutions – including religion – were based on economic foundations, many have seen The Protestant Ethic as turning this theory on its head by implying that a religious movement fostered capitalism, not the other way around.[citation needed]

Other scholars have taken a more nuanced view of Weber's argument. Weber states in the closing of this essay, 'it is, of course, not my aim to substitute for a one-sided materialistic an equally one-sided spiritualistic causal interpretation of culture and history. Each is equally possible, but each if it does not serve as the preparation, but as the conclusion of an investigation, accomplishes equally little in the interest of historical truth.' Weber's argument can be understood as an attempt to deepen the understanding of the cultural origins of capitalism, which does not exclude the historical materialist origins described by Marx: modern capitalism emerged from an elective affinity of 'material; and 'ideal' factors.[2]

Table of contents[edit]

Table of contents from the 1958 Scribner's edition, with section titles added by Talcott Parsons:
Part 1. The Problem

I. Religious Affiliation and Social Stratification
II. The Spirit of Capitalism
III. Luther's Conception of the Calling. Task of the Investigation.

Part 2. The Practical Ethics of the Ascetic Branches of Protestantism.

IV. The Religious Foundations of Worldly Asceticism
A. Calvinism
Predestination; Elimination of Magic; Rationalization of the World; Certainty of Salvation; Lutheranism vs. Calvinism; Catholicism vs. Calvinism; Monasticism vs. Puritanism; Methodical Ethic; Idea of Proof.

Protestant Work Ethic Weber Pdf

B. Pietism
Emotionalism; Spener; Francke; Zinzendorf; German Pietism.
C. Methodism
D. The Baptism Sects
Baptist and Quaker; Sect Principle; Inner Worldly Asceticism; Transformation of the World.
V. Asceticism and the Spirit of Capitalism
Richard Baxter; Meaning of Work; Justification of Profit; Jewish vs. Puritan Capitalism; Puritanism and Culture; Saving and Capital; Paradox of Asceticism and Rich; Serving Both Worlds; Citizenry Capitalistic Ethic; Iron Cage of Capitalism.

Criticisms[edit]

Economic criticism[edit]

The economist and historian Henryk Grossman criticises Weber's analysis on two fronts, firstly with reference to Marx's extensive work which showed that the stringent legal measures taken against poverty and vagabondage was a reaction to the massive population shifts caused by the enclosure of the commons in England. And, secondly, in Grossman's own work showing how this 'bloody legislation' against those who had been put off their land was effected across Europe and especially in France. For Grossman this legislation, the outlawing of idleness and the poorhouses they instituted physically forced people from serfdom into wage-labor. For him, this general fact was not related to Protestantism and so capitalism came largely by force and not by any vocational training regarding an inner-worldliness of Protestantism.[10] However, it is possible that the Protestant 'work ethic' reinforced or legitimized these legal measures within a larger cultural context.

In a paper published on 10 November 2009, Harvard economist Davide Cantoni tested Weber's Protestant hypothesis using population and economic growth in second-millennium Germany as the data set, with negative results. Cantoni writes:

Using population figures in a dataset comprising 276 cities in the years 1300–1900, I find no effects of Protestantism on economic growth. The finding is robust to the inclusion of a variety of controls, and does not appear to depend on data selection or small sample size. In addition, Protestantism has no effect when interacted with other likely determinants of economic development. I also analyze the endogeneity of religious choice; instrumental variables estimates of the effects of Protestantism are similar to the OLS results.[11]

However, Cantoni uses city size, and not relative real wage growth, which was the Weber thesis, as his 'main dependent variable' (Cantoni, 2).

Other recent scholarship continues to find valid Protestant Ethic effects both in historical and contemporary development patterns.

Dudley and Blum write:

Evidence of falling wages in Catholic cities and rising wages in Protestant cities between 1500 and 1750, during the spread of literacy in the vernacular, is inconsistent with most theoretical models of economic growth. In The Protestant Ethic, Weber suggested an alternative explanation based on culture. Here, a theoretical model confirms that a small change in the subjective cost of cooperating with strangers can generate a profound transformation in trading networks. In explaining urban growth in early-modern Europe, specifications compatible with human-capital versions of the neoclassical model and endogenous-growth theory are rejected in favor of a 'small-world' formulation based on the Weber thesis.[12]

Revisionist criticism[edit]

H. M. Robertson, in his book Aspects of Economic Individualism, argued against the historical and religious claims of Weber. Robertson points out that capitalism began to flourish not in Britain, but in 14th century Italy, a decidedly different epoch. Since this is true, then the rise of capitalism cannot be attributed to Adam Smith, the Protestant Reformation, etc. In fact, Robertson goes further, and states that what happened in Britain was rather a retrogression from what was achieved in Italy centuries earlier.

Looking at the history of the development of economic thought, Robertson shows that Adam Smith and David Ricardo did not found economic science de novo. In fact, liberal economic theory was developed by French and Italian Catholics, who were influenced by the Scholastics. The British economic thought was rather a step backwards since it espoused the labor theory of value, which had already been proved incorrect by the School of Salamanca.[13]

Other criticism[edit]

It has recently been suggested that Protestantism has indeed influenced positively the capitalist development of respective social systems not so much through the 'Protestant ethics' but rather through the promotion of literacy.[14]

Becker and Wossmann at the University of Munich,[15] as well as Andrey Korotayev and Daria Khaltourina at the Russian Academy of Sciences,[14] showed that literacy levels differing in religious areas can sufficiently explain the economic gaps cited by Weber. The results were supported even under a concentric diffusion model of Protestantism using distance from Wittenberg as a model.[15]

Support[edit]

In 1958, American sociologist Gerhard Lenski conducted an empirical inquiry into 'religion's impact on politics, economics, and family life' in the Detroit, Mich., area. It revealed, among other insights, that there were significant differences between Catholics on the one hand and (white) Protestants and Jews on the other hand with respect to economics and the sciences. Lenski's data supported basic hypotheses of Weber's work The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. According to Lenski, 'the contribution of Protestantism to material progress have been largely unintended by-products of certain distinctive Protestant traits. This was a central point in Weber's theory.' Lenski noted that more than a hundred years prior to Weber, John Wesley, one of the founders of the Methodist church, had observed that 'diligence and frugality' made Methodists wealthy. 'In an early era, Protestant asceticism and dedication to work, as noted both by Wesley and Weber, seem to have been important patterns of action contributing to economic progress. Both facilitated the accumulation of capital, so critically important to the economic growth and development of nations.'[16]

German theologian Friedrich Wilhelm Graf notes: 'Sociologists of religion like Peter L. Berger and David Martin have interpreted the Protestant revolution in Latin America as implicit support of basic elements of Weber's thesis. [...] At any rate, many pious persons there interpret their transition from the Roman Catholic church to Protestant Pentecostal congregations in terms of a moral idea that promises long-term economic gains through strong innerworldly asceticism. The strict ascetic self-discipline that has been successfully institutionalized in the Pentecostal congregations, the readiness to work more and with greater effort and to take less leisurely attitudes lead many Pentecostal Christians to believe that their new faith in God is supported by their economic successes.'[17]

See also[edit]

References[edit]

  1. ^Max Weber; Peter R. Baehr; Gordon C. Wells (2002). The Protestant ethic and the 'spirit' of capitalism and other writings. Penguin. ISBN978-0-14-043921-2. Retrieved 21 August 2011.
  2. ^ abMcKinnon, AM (2010). 'Elective affinities of the Protestant ethic: Weber and the chemistry of capitalism'(PDF). Sociological Theory. 28 (1): 108–126. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9558.2009.01367.x. hdl:2164/3035.
  3. ^'ISA - International Sociological Association: Books of the Century'. International Sociological Association. 1998. Retrieved 25 July 2012.
  4. ^Green, Elliott (12 May 2016). 'What are the most-cited publications in the social sciences (according to Google Scholar)?'. LSE Imact Blog. London School of Economics.
  5. ^Michael Shea (6 October 2015). 'The Protestant Ethic and the Language of Austerity'. Discover Society.
  6. ^ abcdefghiWeber, Max 'The Protestant Ethic and The Spirit of Capitalism' (Penguin Books, 2002) translated by Peter Baehr and Gordon C. Wells
  7. ^ abcdeReinhard Bendix, Max Weber: an intellectual portrait, University of California Press, 1977
  8. ^Bendix. Max Weber. p. 54.
  9. ^Arthur Mitzman (1970). The Iron Cage: An Historical Interpretation of Max Weber. Transaction Publishers. p. 218. ISBN978-1-4128-3745-3. Retrieved 15 September 2013.
  10. ^Grossman, Henryk (2006) ‘The Beginnings of Capitalism and the New Mass Morality’ Journal of Classical Sociology 6 (2): July
  11. ^David Cantoni, 'The Economic Effects of the Protestant Reformation: Testing the Weber Hypothesis in the German Lands,' November 2009, 'Archived copy'. Archived from the original on 5 December 2009. Retrieved 2 December 2009.CS1 maint: archived copy as title (link)
  12. ^Blum, Ulrich; Dudley, Leonard (February 2001), 'Religion and Economic Growth: Was Weber Right?'(PDF), Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 11 (2): 207–230, archived from the original(PDF) on 7 August 2003
  13. ^Rothbard, Murray N. (February 1957), Catholicism, Protestantism, and Capitalism, Ludwig von Mises Institute, archived from the original on 13 March 2014
  14. ^ abKorotayev A., Malkov A., Khaltourina D. (2006), Introduction to Social Macrodynamics, Moscow: URSS, ISBN5-484-00414-4[1] (Chapter 6: Reconsidering Weber: Literacy and 'the Spirit of Capitalism'). P.87-91.
  15. ^ abBecker, Sascha O. and Wossmann, Ludger. 'Was Weber Wrong? A Human Capital Theory of Protestant Economics History.' Munich Discussion Paper No. 2007-7, 22 January 2007. http://epub.ub.uni-muenchen.de/1366/1/weberLMU.pdf.
  16. ^Gerhard Lenski (1963), The Religious Factor: A Sociological Study of Religion's Impact on Politics, Economics. and Family Life, Revised Edition, Garden City, N.Y., pp. 350-352
  17. ^Friedrich Wilhelm Graf (2010), Der Protestantismus. Geschichte und Gegenwart, Second, Revised Edition, Munich (Germany), pp. 116-117

Further reading[edit]

  • Mill, John Stuart. On Liberty: A Translation into Modern English. ISR Publications, 2013. 'Editorial foreword: Christianity and liberty'. [2]
  • Albrow, Martin. (1990). Max Weber’s Construction of Social Theory. London: MacMillan
  • McKinnon, AM (2010). 'Elective affinities of the Protestant ethic: Weber and the chemistry of capitalism'(PDF). Sociological Theory. 28 (1): 108–126. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9558.2009.01367.x. hdl:2164/3035.
  • O’Toole, Roger. (1984). Religion: Classical Sociological Approaches. Toronto: McGraw Hill.
  • Parkin, Frank. (1983). Max Weber. London and New York: Routledge
  • Poggi, Gianfranco. (1983). Calvinism and the Capitalist Spirit: Max Weber’s Protestant Ethic. Amherst: University of Massachusetts Press
  • Shea, Michael (2015)'The Protestant Ethic and the Language of Austerity'. Discover Society. 6 October 2015.

External links[edit]

  • The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism as 'prosperity classic'. Commentary by Tom Butler-Bowdon
  • Max Weber, The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, (Norton Critical Editions, 2009), Introduction by Richard Swedberg
  • Benjamin, Franklin (1748), Advice to a Young Tradesman
Retrieved from 'https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=The_Protestant_Ethic_and_the_Spirit_of_Capitalism&oldid=917955895'
Cover of the original German edition of The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism

The Protestant work ethic, the Calvinist work ethic,[1] or the Puritan work ethic[2] is a work ethic concept in theology, sociology, economics and history that emphasizes that hard work, discipline, and frugality[3] are a result of a person's subscription to the values espoused by the Protestant faith, particularly Calvinism.

The phrase was initially coined in 1904–1905[a] by Max Weber in his book The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism.[4] Weber asserted that Protestant ethics and values along with the Calvinist doctrine of asceticism and predestination gave birth to capitalism.[5] It’s one of the most influential and cited books in sociology although the thesis presented has been controversial since release. Historians such as Fernand Braudel and Hugh Trevor-Roper assert that the Protestant work ethic did not create capitalism and that capitalism developed in pre-Reformation Catholic communities.

Basis in Protestant theology[edit]

Protestants, beginning with Martin Luther, reconceptualized worldly work as a duty which benefits both the individual and society as a whole. Thus, the Catholic idea of good works was transformed into an obligation to consistently work diligently as a sign of grace. Whereas Catholicism teaches that good works are required of Catholics as a necessary manifestation of the faith they received, and that faith apart from works is dead (James 2:14–26) and barren, the Calvinist theologians taught that only those who were predestined to be saved would be saved.

Since it was impossible to know who was predestined, the notion developed that it might be possible to discern that a person was elect (predestined) by observing their way of life. Hard work and frugality were thought to be two important consequences of being one of the elect. Protestants were thus attracted to these qualities and supposed to strive for reaching them.

American political history[edit]

Writer Frank Chodorov argued that the Protestant ethic was long considered indispensable for American political figures:

There was a time, in these United States, when a candidate for public office could qualify with the electorate only by fixing his birthplace in or near the 'log cabin.' He may have acquired a competence, or even a fortune, since then, but it was in the tradition that he must have been born of poor parents and made his way up the ladder by sheer ability, self-reliance, and perseverance in the face of hardship. In short, he had to be 'self made.' The so-called Protestant Ethic then prevalent held that man was a sturdy and responsible individual, responsible to himself, his society, and his God. Anybody who could not measure up to that standard could not qualify for public office or even popular respect. One who was born 'with a silver spoon in his mouth' might be envied, but he could not aspire to public acclaim; he had to live out his life in the seclusion of his own class.[6]

Some political scientists have described the term as a myth invented to assert White Anglo-Saxon Protestant superiority.[7] Many have connected this belief to racism.[8][9] For example, Martin Luther King, Jr. said:

We have deluded ourselves into believing the myth that capitalism grew and prospered out of the Protestant ethic of hard work and sacrifice. The fact is that capitalism was built on the exploitation and suffering of black slaves and continues to thrive on the exploitation of the poor — both black and white, here and abroad.[10]

Support[edit]

There has been a revitalization of Weber's interest, including the work of Lawrence Harrison, Samuel P. Huntington, and David Landes. In a New York Times article, published in June 8, 2003, Niall Ferguson pointed that data from the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) seems to confirm that 'the experience of Western Europe in the past quarter-century offers an unexpected confirmation of the Protestant ethic. To put it bluntly, we are witnessing the decline and fall of the Protestant work ethic in Europe. This represents the stunning triumph of secularization in Western Europe—the simultaneous decline of both Protestantism and its unique work ethic.'[11]

Criticism[edit]

Joseph Schumpeter argued that capitalism began in Italy in the 14th century, not in the Protestant areas of Europe.[12] Other factors that further developed the European market economy included the strengthening of property rights and lowering of transaction costs with the decline and monetization of feudalism, and the increase in real wages following the epidemics of bubonic plague.[13]

Sascha Becker and Ludger Wossmann at the University of Munich have written a discussion paper describing an alternate theory. The abstract to this states that the literacy gap between Protestants (as a result of the Reformation) and Catholics sufficiently explains the economic gaps, and that the '[r]esults hold when we exploit the initial concentric dispersion of the Reformation to use distance to Wittenberg as an instrument for Protestantism.'[14] However, they also note that, between Luther (1500) and 1871 Prussia, the limited data available has meant that the period in question is regarded as a 'black box' and that only 'some cursory discussion and analysis' is possible.[15]

Historian Fernand Braudel wrote 'all historians have opposed this tenuous theory [the Protestant Ethic], although they have not managed to be rid of it once and for all. Yet it is clearly false. The northern countries took over the place that earlier had been so long and brilliantly been occupied by the old capitalist centers of the Mediterranean. They invented nothing, either in technology or business management.'[16]

Social scientist Rodney Stark comments that 'during their critical period of economic development, these northern centers of capitalism were Catholic, not Protestant — the Reformation still lay well into the future.' He also summarized the finding of other leading modern historians thus, 'Protestants were not more likely to hold the high-status capitalist positions than were Catholics. Catholic areas of western Europe did not lag in their industrial development. And even more obvious at the time Weber wrote was that fully developed capitalism had appeared in Europe many centuries before the Reformation!'[17] British historian Hugh Trevor-Roper said, 'The idea that large-scale industrial capitalism was ideologically impossible before the Reformation is exploded by the simple fact that it existed.'[18]

See also[edit]

Notes[edit]

  1. ^No exact date is known. The term appeared to the public with the publication of his book in 1905.

References[edit]

  1. ^The Idea of Work in Europe from Antiquity to Modern Times by Catharina Lis
  2. ^Ryken, Leland (2010). Worldly Saints: The Puritans As They Really Were. Harper Collins. pp. 51–. ISBN978-0-310-87428-7.]
  3. ^'Protestant Ethic'. Believe: Religious Information Source.
  4. ^Weber, Max (2003) [First published 1905]. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. Translated by Parsons, Talcott. New York: Dover. ISBN9780486122373.
  5. ^https://www.tutor2u.net/sociology/reference/sociology-weber-calvinism-and-spirit-of-modern-capitalism
  6. ^Chodorov, Frank (21 March 2011). 'The Radical Rich'. Mises Daily Articles. Mises Institute.
  7. ^https://www.thegospelcoalition.org/article/the-myth-of-the-protestant-work-ethic/
  8. ^https://www.semanticscholar.org/paper/Protestant-work-ethic's-relation-to-intergroup-and-Rosenthal-Levy/6d75a317aeb8db7d17fd02505d427beff4990fe7
  9. ^https://newrepublic.com/article/121901/white-protestant-roots-american-racism
  10. ^https://www.pri.org/stories/2017-12-04/smiley-capitalism-has-always-been-built-back-poor-both-black-and-white
  11. ^Ferguson, Niall (8 June 2003). 'The World; Why America Outpaces Europe (Clue: The God Factor)'. The New York Times. Retrieved 2011-09-19.
  12. ^Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1994), 'Part II From the Beginning to the First Classical Situation (to about 1790), chapter 2 The scholastic Doctors and the Philosophers of Natural Law', History of Economic Analysis, pp. 74–75, ISBN978-0-415-10888-1, OCLC269819. In the footnote, Schumpeter refers to Usher, Abbott Payson (1943). The Early History of Deposit Banking in Mediterranean Europe. Harvard economic studies ;v. 75. Harvard university press. and de Roover, Raymond (December 1942). 'Money, Banking, and Credit in Medieval Bruges'. Journal of Economic History. 2, supplement S1: 52–65. doi:10.1017/S0022050700083431.
  13. ^Voigtlander, Nico; Voth, Hans-Joachim (9 October 2012). 'The Three Horsemen of Riches: Plague, War, and Urbanization in Early Modern Europe'(PDF). The Review of Economic Studies. 80 (2): 774–811. CiteSeerX10.1.1.303.2638. doi:10.1093/restud/rds034.
  14. ^Becker, Sascha O.; Wößmann, Ludger (2007), Was Weber Wrong? A Human Capital Theory of Protestant Economic History - Munich Discussion Paper No. 2007-7(PDF), Munich: Department of Economics University of Munich, retrieved 12 September 2012
  15. ^Becker, Wossmann (2007) page A5 Appendix B
  16. ^Braudel, Fernand. 1977. Afterthoughts on Material Civilization and Capitalism. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
  17. ^'Protestant Modernity'.
  18. ^Trevor-Roper. 2001. The Crisis of the Seventeenth Century. Liberty Fund

Further reading[edit]

Quotations related to Protestant work ethic at Wikiquote

  • Sascha O. Becker and Ludger Wossmann. 'Was Weber Wrong? A Human Capital Theory of Protestant Economics History'. Munich Discussion Paper No. 2007-7, 22 January 2007. http://epub.ub.uni-muenchen.de/1366/1/weberLMU.pdf
  • Frey, Donald (August 14, 2001), 'Protestant Ethic Thesis', in Robert Whaples (ed.), EH.Net Encyclopedia, archived from the original on 2014-03-28
  • Robert Green, editor. The Weber Thesis Controversy. D.C. Heath, 1973, covers some of the criticism of Weber's theory.
  • Hill, Roger B. (1992), Historical Context of the Work Ethic, archived from the original on 2012-08-17
  • McKinnon, Andrew (2010). 'Elective affinities of the Protestant ethic: Weber and the chemistry of capitalism'(PDF). Sociological Theory. 28 (1): 108–126. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9558.2009.01367.x.
  • Max Weber. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. Chas. Scribner's sons, 1959.
Retrieved from 'https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Protestant_work_ethic&oldid=915867511'